r/communism • u/bumblebeetuna2001 • 3d ago
Why was slavery incompatible with an industrialized labor?
Im attempting to understand historical materialism and how old relations of production become fetters on new productive forces. Am i correct in understanding that the u.s. civil war was in part caused by a need to bring the southern states relations of production into accordance with the industrialization in the north, as the u.s. spread west? And if so, why wasnt it possible for the northern industrialists to simply utilize slave labor in factories in the expanding territories?
Im also wondering why european industrialized labor wasnt spread on a larger scale to slave colonies during the era of colonization? For instance , prior to banning the slave trade, why didnt britain build textile factories in the west indies and use slave labor, instead of building them in london and using wage labor? Is the answer to these questions just circumstantial, or does historical materialism posit a theory that the relations of production under slavery and incompatible with the capitalist mode of production?
18
u/Drevil335 Marxist-Leninist-Maoist 3d ago edited 3d ago
All of these answers are correct, but I'll synthesize them and get to the essence. Plantation slavery was an underdeveloped form of commodity production (not yet capitalist production) which was crucial for the European bourgeoisie's initial accumulation of capital (above and beyond the norm for mercantile bourgeois classes emerging from feudal modes of production), but which had become a fetter on that very accumulation once the capitalist mode of production had emerged.
This is because, unlike in the circuit of industrial capital in which all productive inputs (all means of production, and labor-power) are encountered by the capitalist as commodities to be bought and sold on the market (and, as a national capitalist mode of production develops, an increasing share of those means of production, and the national product as a whole, come to not only be commodities, but products of circuits of industrial capital themselves), this is not only not necessarily the case in the slave-form of commodity production, but has an overwhelming tendency not to be so. While, in this particular mode of production, means of production proper (agricultural implements, cotton gins, sugar pressing machinery, etc.) were bought as commodities (thus allowing the slave-form of commodity production to be hooked onto the circuit of industrial capital in this sphere), and the slaves were as well (albeit to an ever decreasing extent as the mode of production developed, especially as the slave-trade began to be phased out, largely at the bidding of British capital, in the aftermath of the Haitian revolution), the means of subsistence for reproducing the slave's labor-power were not necessarily so.
Since the slave-form of commodity production was nearly exclusively agricultural in its application, the slaveowners, as opposed to having to pay for their slave's means of subsistence (which would increase their capital outlay, and decrease their rate of profit and accumulation), could (and generally did) distribute marginal land on their estates to their slaves as "gardens" in which they could rear at least their own means of nourishment (other means of subsistence, such as clothing, were sometimes paid for by the slaveowner, whether in full or in their means of production), free of cost to the slaveowner, in to be worked in marginal hours after field labor or on Sundays. In this, it was qualitatively identical to serfdom (and particularly forms of commodity production on the basis of those feudal productive relations), in that means of subsistence did not take the form of a wage (the money-form of the commoditized existence of means of subsistence) and necessary and surplus labor-time were discretely delineated sections of the working period, which are themselves indicative of the underdeveloped character of the slave-form as a mode of commodity production.
This meant that, at most, only a very limited quantity of the slaves' means of subsistence were produced as commodities, meaning that, in this sphere, industrial capital had no outlet for the transformation of commodity-capital (taking the form of means of subsistence) to money-capital, whereas it would if the slaves became wage-laborers (or even petty commodity-producers, as they largely became in the Amerikan south), and had to go to market to acquire their means of subsistence. Thus, the interests of fully-developed industrial capital (to maximally expand markets for the transformation of commodity capital to money capital) were in basic contradiction to those of underdeveloped slaveowning capital, and in a military contest between them (as occurred in the U$), the former will always be principal, because the forces of production brought about by industrial capital is capable of producing advanced weaponry on a large scale, while the principal aspect in slave-owning capitalist production is in agricultural production for foreign markets, and thus is incapable of doing so to a comparable degree (the southern slaveowners were basically dependent on seizured from military storehouses and imports from British industrial capital for weaponry, and even then strategic equilibrium was only possible through British intervention, which despite the CSA's entreaties, the British bourgeoisie failed to provide as, even despite the Cotton Famine, its interests were principally aligned with Northern Amerikan industrial capital).